As productivity growth continues to stall in the developed
world, Rachel Connolly asks, can frontier firms give some insight into the
solution?
Solving the productivity growth puzzle holds the
key to an increase in wages and living standards
It is hard to overstate
the role productivity has played in the prosperity we enjoy in the developed
world today, and harder still to exaggerate the dire ramifications we now face
as the OECD’s productivity growth grinds to a halt. The patchwork of reasons
offered to explain the slowdown in production has failed to pinpoint the true
cause, but recent research into ‘frontier firms’ has suggested they may provide
some clue as to the solution.
Coined by Paul Krugman,
the widely adopted assertion “productivity isn’t everything, but in the long
run it is almost everything” identifies two crucial points: first, the extent
to which productivity shapes an economy, and second, the metric through which
we discuss productivity’s impact on living standards.
Productivity, by
definition, is the fraction of GDP produced per hour worked, so it’s easy to
see the vital role any growth in productivity plays in the wealth of a nation.
It’s also important to note – in terms of raising living standards – growth
should be considered relative to a state’s own past, and not compared to other
countries.
Historically, high
levels of productivity growth have afforded citizens of the developed world
privileges so ubiquitous they have been construed as rights, but this may not
be the case for coming generations. Until 2000, OECD area countries maintained
a steady growth rate of around two percent year-on-year, while in emerging markets
this was often zero, or even negative. This is why living conditions in richer
countries improved colossally in the second half of the 20th century while
developing economies witnessed little change.
However, in the years
prior to the global financial crisis, productivity growth in the OECD area
began to falter, eventually coming to a dead halt in 2008. Despite a brief
period of improvement in 2010, growth in the OECD area has never fully
recovered, and now stands at around one percent.
High levels of
productivity growth have afforded
citizens of the developed world privileges they have construed as rights, but this may not be the case for coming generations
citizens of the developed world privileges they have construed as rights, but this may not be the case for coming generations
This sluggish
productivity will likely create two distinct problems for younger generations:
for the first time in living memory, children in the developed world won’t
experience a better quality of life than their parents, and, perhaps more
worryingly, with debt payments contingent on GDP rising, developed countries
will struggle to pay off mounting levels of public and private debt.
Unproductive
problems
the stall in productivity has been particularly pronounced in Europe: in 1995, productivity growth in Europe stood on par with the rest of the world at two percent, but has since slumped to 0.5 percent. This figure trails the 3.2 percent registered in emerging economies, as well as the one percent posted in the stalling US.
the stall in productivity has been particularly pronounced in Europe: in 1995, productivity growth in Europe stood on par with the rest of the world at two percent, but has since slumped to 0.5 percent. This figure trails the 3.2 percent registered in emerging economies, as well as the one percent posted in the stalling US.
Ageing populations and a
fall in the number of births within the euro zone have only acted to compound
the issue, with the workforce expected to shrink in the coming years.
Therefore, if productivity remains flat, GDP is expected to fall across Europe.
In the worst-case scenario, GDP could decrease by as much as 14 percent in
Germany, 16 percent in Italy and 22 percent in Spain by 2050.
The effects of this
slowdown are already visible in the UK, where productivity growth has been
among the worst in Europe. Since the recession, wage growth in the UK has been
paltry, with data published by the OECD showing wages grew faster in France,
Germany and Italy. This downturn has also impacted public investment, with
literacy among the UK’s 18 to 24 year-olds trailing Europe’s elite.
But, while the problems
resulting from a slowdown in productivity are clear, the reasons behind the
slump are less so. Productivity growth is driven by labour saving inventions,
and is, therefore, contingent on firms investing funds into new technologies. A
lack of investment during the recession has not helped the problem, but,
equally, cannot be held wholly accountable, as the slowdown predates the
financial crisis. Some economists, notably Robert Gordon, argue the problem is
due to a lack of good innovation, rather than a lack of investment.
Frontier
firms vs. laggard firms
however, recent research examining so-called ‘frontier firms’ casts doubt on Gordon’s pessimistic take. Frontier firms are companies that exist at the top end of productivity in any industry. Tech companies such as Google or Amazon are obvious examples of frontier firms, as are the likes of BMW, L’Oréal and Nestlé. Firms like these are often quick to adopt new technologies and implement innovative management practices, meaning if Gordon is correct, and the fault lies with technology, then these companies should have also suffered a slowdown in productivity – this has not been the case.
however, recent research examining so-called ‘frontier firms’ casts doubt on Gordon’s pessimistic take. Frontier firms are companies that exist at the top end of productivity in any industry. Tech companies such as Google or Amazon are obvious examples of frontier firms, as are the likes of BMW, L’Oréal and Nestlé. Firms like these are often quick to adopt new technologies and implement innovative management practices, meaning if Gordon is correct, and the fault lies with technology, then these companies should have also suffered a slowdown in productivity – this has not been the case.
Speaking to ,
Daniel Andrews, a senior economist at the OECD and author of Frontier Firms, Technology
Diffusion and Public Policy,
said: “Productivity performance [among these firms has] continued to grow quite
strongly… the problem was everyone else, or, rather, what we call laggard
firms.”
With wage growth
across OECD countries remaining low since the recession, companies haven’t been
forced to invest in labour saving innovations… simply put, the cost of
investing in new equipment isn’t worthwhile
While frontier firms are
still investing and innovating, Andrews believes “the benefits of their innovation
and productivity aren’t diffusing to everyone else”. Andrews explained this
discrepancy between hyper productive firms and laggards may lead to an upheaval
in developed economies: “What we had before was a growth model in which the
most technologically advanced firms innovate and the benefits of these
innovations spill over into other firms, that has essentially driven economic
growth for the last 50 years or so – since the Second World War. There seems to
be a number of indications that process has broken down in the early 2000s.”
The reason for this lack
of “innovation diffusion”, as Andrews calls it, is still unclear. Certainly,
the cost of implementing new technologies is one barrier. But Andrews also
cites bad management, and the fact laggard firms are “not doing the things that
are complementary to technology adoption”.
As Andrews is quick to
point out, if firms lack a carrot, they also lack a stick. With wage growth
across OECD countries remaining low since the recession, companies haven’t been
forced to invest in labour saving innovations. Simply put, with labour so
cheap, the cost of investing in new equipment isn’t worthwhile.
“This is also about lack
of competition in the market”, Andrews said. “Zombie firms – that is really
weak firms – are increasingly able to survive in the market because they’re
kept alive by creditors and weak banks.”
Frontier firms like Google are often the quickest to develop new
technologies and innovative management processes
Developing
frontier skills
there have, of course, always been frontier firms, but a combination of globalization and heightened connectivity has given rise to what Andrews calls “winner takes all dynamics”. Andrews suggests this could occur even if firms were only “fractionally better than the next best firm”, with the best digital technology firms able to “essentially capture all of the market”.
there have, of course, always been frontier firms, but a combination of globalization and heightened connectivity has given rise to what Andrews calls “winner takes all dynamics”. Andrews suggests this could occur even if firms were only “fractionally better than the next best firm”, with the best digital technology firms able to “essentially capture all of the market”.
A troubling side effect
of the breakdown in innovation diffusion is the negative impact it seems to
have on wages, with a growing inequality between salaries at frontier firms and
their laggard counterparts.
Andrews also identified
a mismatch in the level of skill: “On average across the OECD, about one
quarter of workers have skills that don’t align with their job… its
two-and-a-half times more likely that this reflects over skilling than under
skilling… there are a lot of talented people trapped in quite marginal firms.”
The wage divergence
between frontier firms and laggards means not only are talented people trapped
in low skill jobs, they are also trapped with low wages. This may mean that, on
top of a decline in living standards, the productivity crisis will limit the
skills and salaries of future generations, with frontier firms hiring
relatively few people.
The wage divergence
between frontier firms and laggards means not only are talented people trapped
in low skill jobs, they are also trapped with low wages
According to How Morris,
an advisor to the Education Secretary in Wales, this is increasingly becoming
an area of policy focus. Morris said: “[Frontier firms] tend to take on a small
number of very, very skilled young people; they’re not interested in the bulk
of graduates.” The opportunities to join a frontier firm also diminish as a
person climbs the career ladder, and Morris believes this is compounded
“because young people have indebted themselves so much, they’re not able to pay
for their own training later in life”.
Morris also suggests our
education systems are increasingly ill equipped to provide people with the
necessary skills for a changing economy: “Technology is moving so quickly that
lecturers in universities don’t have the skills to teach what industry wants”.
This has been made worse by a lack of in-work training. Morris added: “I
anticipate people in their 20s now, as they move up the career ladder will tell
younger generations to think twice before doing a degree.”
Therefore, in order to
avoid a future in which living standards are frozen and pay varies drastically
depending on the employer, the productivity problem needs to be solved.
Encouraging innovation diffusion throughout the entire economy will be key to
any solution, and this could take the form of levies on companies failing to
invest in staff training, schemes in which senior staff from frontier firms
teach good management practices to those in laggard firms, or even a rethink of
traditional one-subject degrees.
As Andrews puts it: “[The]
productivity benefits are potentially unbounded, so you don’t want to come down
too hard on frontier firms… but there are challenges to [the] old policy [which
need to be] raised.”
Comments
Post a Comment